Money and Time Preference
(By Saifedean Ammous)
Sound money is chosen freely on the market for its salability, because it
holds its value across time, because it can transfer value effectively across
space, and because it can be divided and grouped into small and large
scales. It is money whose supply cannot be manipulated by a coercive
authority that imposes its use on others. From the preceding discussion, and
from the understanding of monetary economics afforded to us by Austrian
economics, the importance of sound money can be explained for three
broad reasons: first, it protects value across time, which gives people a
bigger incentive to think of their future, and lowers their time preference.
The lowering of the time preference is what initiates the process of human
civilization and allows for humans to cooperate, prosper, and live in peace.
Second, sound money allows for trade to be based on a stable unit of
measurement, facilitating ever-larger markets, free from government
control and coercion, and with free trade comes peace and prosperity.
Further, a unit of account is essential for all forms of economic calculation
and planning, and unsound money makes economic calculation unreliable
and is the root cause of economic recessions and crises. Finally, sound
money is an essential requirement for individual freedom from despotism
and repression, as the ability of a coercive state to create money can give it
undue power over its subjects, power which by its very nature will attract
the least worthy, and most immoral, to take its reins.
Sound money is a prime factor in determining individual time preference,
an enormously important and widely neglected aspect of individual decision
making. Time preference refers to the ratio at which individuals value the
present compared to the future. Because humans do not live eternally, death
could come to us at any point in time, making the future uncertain. And
because consumption is necessary for survival, people always value present
consumption more than future consumption, as the lack of present
consumption could make the future never arrive. In other words, time
preference is positive for all humans; there is always a discount on the
future compared to the present.
Further, because more goods can be produced with time and resources,
rational individuals would always prefer to have a given quantity of
resources in the present than in the future, as they could use them to
produce more. For an individual to be willing to defer her receipt of a good
by a year, she would have to be offered a larger quantity of the good. The
increase necessary to tempt an individual to delay her receipt of the good is
what determines her time preference. All rational individuals have a
nonzero time preference, but the time preference varies from one individual
to another.
Animals’ time preference is far higher than humans’, as they act to the
satisfaction of their immediate instinctive impulses and have little
conception of the future. A few animals are capable of building nests or
homes that can last for the future, and these have a lower time preference
than the animals that act to the satisfaction of their immediate needs such as
hunger and aggression. Human beings' lower time preference allows us to
curb our instinctive and animalistic impulses, think of what is better for our
future, and act rationally rather than impulsively. Instead of spending all our
time producing goods for immediate consumption, we can choose to spend
time engaged in production of goods that will take longer to complete, if
they are superior goods. As humans reduce their time preference, they
develop the scope for carrying out tasks over longer time horizons, for
satisfaction of ever-more remote needs, and they develop the mental
capacity to create goods not for immediate consumption but for the
production of future goods, in other words, to create capital goods.
Whereas animals and humans can both hunt, humans differentiated
themselves from animals by spending time developing tools for hunting.
Some animals may occasionally use a tool in hunting another animal, but
they have no capacity for owning these tools and maintaining them for
long-term use. Only through a lower time preference can a human decide to
take time away from hunting and dedicate that time to building a spear or
fishing rod that cannot be eaten itself, but can allow him to hunt more
proficiently. This is the essence of investment: as humans delay immediate
gratification, they invest their time and resources in the production of
capital goods which will make production more sophisticated or
technologically advanced and extend it over a longer time-horizon. The
only reason that an individual would choose to delay his gratification to
engage in risky production over a longer period of time is that these longer
processes will generate more output and superior goods. In other words,
investment raises the productivity of the producer.
Economist Hans-Hermann Hoppe explains that once time preference drops
enough to allow for any savings and capital or durable consumer-goods
formation at all, the tendency is for time preference to drop even further as
a “process of civilization” is initiated.+
The fisherman who builds a fishing rod is able to catch more fish per hour
than the fisherman hunting with his bare hands. But the only way to build
the fishing rod is to dedicate an initial amount of time to work that does not
produce edible fish, but instead produces a fishing rod. This is an uncertain
process, for the fishing rod might not work and the fisherman will have
wasted his time to no avail. Not only does investment require delaying
gratification, it also always carries with it a risk of failure, which means the
investment will only be undertaken with an expectation of a reward. The
lower an individual's time preference, the more likely he is to engage in
investment, to delay gratification, and to accumulate capital. The more
capital is accumulated, the higher the productivity of labor, and the longer
the time horizon of production.
To understand the difference more vividly, contrast two hypothetical
individuals who start off with nothing but their bare hands, and differing
time preferences: Harry has a higher time preference than Linda. Harry
chooses to only spend his time catching fish with his hands, needing about
eight hours a day to catch enough fish to feed himself for the day. Linda, on
the other hand, having a lower time preference, spends only six hours
catching fish, making do with a smaller amount of fish every day, and
spends the other two hours working on building a fishing rod. After a week
has passed, Linda has succeeded in building a working fishing rod. In the
second week, she can catch in eight hours double the quantity of fish which
Harry catches. Linda's investment in the fishing rod could allow her to work
for only four hours a day and eat the same amount of fish Harry eats, but
because she has a lower time preference, she will not rest on her laurels.
She will instead spend four hours catching as many fish as Harry catches in
eight hours, and then spend another four hours engaged in further capital
accumulation, building herself a fishing boat, for instance. A month later,
Linda has a fishing rod and a boat that allows her to go deeper into the sea,
to catch fish that Harry had never even seen. Linda's productivity is not just
higher per hour; her fish are different from, and superior to, the ones Harry
catches. She now only needs one hour of fishing to secure her food for a
day, and so she dedicates the rest of her time to even more capital
accumulation, building better and bigger fishing rods, nets, and boats,
which in turn increases her productivity further and improves the quality of
her life.
Should Harry and his descendants continue to work and consume with the
same time preference, they will continue to live the same life he lived, with
the same level of consumption and productivity. Should Linda and her
descendants continue with the same lower time preference, they will
continuously improve their quality of life over time, increasing their stock
of capital and engaging in labor with ever-higher levels of productivity, in
processes that take far longer to complete. The real-life equivalents of the
descendants of Linda would today be the owners of Annelies Ilena, the
world's largest fishing trawler. This formidable machine took decades to
conceive, design, and build before it was completed in the year 2000, and it
will continue to operate for decades to offer the lower-time-preference
investors in it a return on the capital they provided to the building process
many decades ago. The process of producing fish for Linda's descendants
has become so long and sophisticated it takes decades to complete, whereas
Harry's descendants still complete their process in a few hours every day.
The difference, of course, is that Linda's descendants have vastly higher
productivity than Harry's, and that's what makes engaging in the longer
process worthwhile.
An important demonstration of the importance of time preference comes
from the famous Stanford marshmallow experiment, conducted in the late
1960s. Psychologist Walter Mischel would leave children in a room with a
piece of marshmallow or a cookie, and tell the kids they were free to have it
if they wanted, but that he will come back in 15 minutes, and if the children
had not eaten the candy, he would offer them a second piece as a reward. In
other words, the children had the choice between the immediate
gratification of a piece of candy, or delaying gratification and receiving two
pieces of candy. This is a simple way of testing children's time preference:
students with a lower time preference were the ones who could wait for the
second piece of candy, whereas the students with the higher time preference
could not. Mischel followed up with the children decades later and found
significant correlation between having a low time preference as measured
with the marshmallow test and good academic achievement, high SAT
score, low body mass index, and lack of addiction to drugs.
As an economics professor, I make sure to teach the marshmallow
experiment in every course I teach, as I believe it is the single most
important lesson economics can teach to individuals, and am astounded that
university curricula in economics have almost entirely ignored this lesson,
to the point that many academic economists have no familiarity with the
term time preference altogether or its significance.
While microeconomics has focused on transactions between individuals,
and macroeconomics on the role of government in the economy, the reality
is that the most important economic decisions to any individual's well-being
are the ones they conduct in their trade-offs with their future self. Every
day, an individual will conduct a few economic transactions with other
people, but they will partake in a far larger number of transactions with
their future self. The examples of these trades are infinite: deciding to save
money rather than spend it; deciding to invest in acquiring skills for future
employment rather than seeking immediate employment with low pay;
buying a functional and affordable car rather than getting into debt for an
expensive car; working overtime rather than going out to party with friends;
or, my favorite example to use in class: deciding to study the course
material every week of the semester rather than cramming the night before
the final exam.
In each of these examples, there is nobody forcing the decision on the
individual, and the prime beneficiary or loser from the consequences of
these choices is the individual himself. The main factor determining a man's
choices in life is his time preference. While people's time preference and
self-control will vary from one situation to the other, in general, a strong
correlation can be found across all aspects of decision making. The
sobering reality to keep in mind is that a man's lot in life will be largely
determined by these trades between him and his future self. As much as
he'd like to blame others for his failures, or credit others with his success,
the infinite trades he took with himself are likely to be more significant than
any outside circumstances or conditions. No matter how circumstances
conspire against the man with a low time preference, he will probably find a
way to keep prioritizing his future self until he achieves his objectives. And
no matter how much fortune favors the man with a high time preference, he
will find a way to continue sabotaging and shortchanging his future self.
The many stories of people who have triumphed against all odds and
unfavorable circumstances stand in stark contrast to the stories of people
blessed with skills and talent that rewarded them handsomely, who
nonetheless managed to waste all that talent and achieve no lasting good for
themselves. Many professional athletes and entertainers, gifted with talents
that earn them large sums of money, nevertheless die penniless as their high
time preference gets the better of them. On the other hand, many ordinary
people with no special talents work diligently and save and invest for a
lifetime to achieve financial security and bequeath their children a life
better than the one they inherited.
It is only through the lowering of time preference that individuals begin to
appreciate investing in the long run and start prioritizing future outcomes. A
society in which individuals bequeath their children more than what they
received from their parents is a civilized society: it is a place where life is
improving, and people live with a purpose of making the next generation's
lives better. As society's capital levels continue to increase, productivity
increases and, along with it, quality of life. The security of their basic needs
assured, and the dangers of the environment averted, people turn their
attention toward more profound aspects of life than material well-being and
the drudgery of work. They cultivate families and social ties; undertake
cultural, artistic, and literary projects; and seek to offer lasting contributions
to their community and the world. Civilization is not about more capital
accumulation per se; rather, it is about what capital accumulation allows
humans to achieve, the flourishing and freedom to seek higher meaning in
life when their base needs are met and most pressing dangers averted.
There are many factors that come into play in determining the time
preference of individuals. Security of people in their person and property is
arguably one of the most important. Individuals who live in areas of conflict
and crime will have a significant chance of losing their life and are thus
likely to more highly discount the future, resulting in a higher time
preference than those who live in peaceful societies. Security of property is
another major factor influencing individuals’ time preference: societies
where governments or thieves are likely to expropriate individuals’ property
capriciously would have higher time preference, as such actions would
drive individuals to prioritize spending their resources on immediate
gratification rather than investing them in property which could be
appropriated at any time. Tax rates will also adversely affect time
preference: the higher the taxes, the less of their income that individuals are
allowed to keep; this would lead to individuals working less at the margin
and saving less for their future, because the burden of taxes is more likely to
reduce savings than consumption, particularly for those with a low income,
most of which is needed for basic survival.
The factor affecting time preference that is most relevant to our discussion,
however, is the expected future value of money. In a free market where
people are free to choose their money, they will choose the form of money
most likely to hold its value over time. The better the money is at holding
its value, the more it incentivizes people to delay consumption and instead
dedicate resources for production in the future, leading to capital
accumulation and improvement of living standards, while also engendering
in people a low time preference in other, non-economic aspects of their life.
When economic decision making is geared toward the future, it is natural
that all manner of decisions are geared toward the future as well. People
become more peaceful and cooperative, understanding that cooperation is a
far more rewarding long-term strategy than any short-term gains from
conflict. People develop a strong sense of morality, prioritizing the moral
choices that will cause the best long-term outcomes for them and their
children. A person who thinks of the long run is less likely to cheat, lie, or
steal, because the reward for such activities may be positive in the short run,
but can be devastatingly negative in the long run.
The reduction in the purchasing power of money is similar to a form of
taxation or expropriation, reducing the real value of one's money even while
the nominal value is constant. In modern economies government-issued
money is inextricably linked to artificially lower interest rates, which is a
desirable goal for modern economists because it promotes borrowing and
investing. But the effect of this manipulation of the price of capital is to
artificially reduce the interest rate that accrues to savers and investors, as
well as the one paid by borrowers. The natural implication of this process is
to reduce savings and increase borrowing. At the margin, individuals will
consume more of their income and borrow more against the future. This
will not just have implications on their time preference in financial
decisions; it will likely reflect on everything in their lives.
The move from money that holds its value or appreciates to money that
loses its value is very significant in the long run: society saves less,
accumulates less capital, and possibly begins to consume its capital; worker
productivity stays constant or declines, resulting in the stagnation of real
wages, even if nominal wages can be made to increase through the magical
power of printing ever more depreciating pieces of paper money. As people
start spending more and saving less, they become more present-oriented in
all their decision making, resulting in moral failings and a likelihood to
engage in conflict and destructive and self-destructive behavior.
This helps explain why civilizations prosper under a sound monetary
system, but disintegrate when their monetary systems are debased, as was
the case with the Romans, the Byzantines, and modern European societies.
The contrast between the nineteenth and twentieth centuries can be
understood in the context of the move away from sound money and all the
attendant problems that creates.
This text is taken from the book: "THE BITCOIN STANDARD"