pull down to refresh

We have an answer from James Buchanan, who has a book of collected essays titled “What Should Economists Do?” in which the first chapter lent its title to the whole collection. Buchanan notes that to answer the question, he had to “proceed squarely against the advice of a modern economist whose opinions I regard with respect, George Stigler.” Stigler said “that it is folly to become concerned with methodology before the age of sixty-five.” Buchanan also quotes Jacob Viner’s tautology, “economics is what economists do,” and Frank Knight’s reversal, “economists are those who do economics.”
After the humor, Buchanan gives us his answer: economists should focus on markets, not resource allocation. Even though many principles texts include resource allocation in their definitions of economics, Buchanan argues that economists ought to study “the various institutional arrangements that arise as a result of this form of activity.” By focusing on resource allocation, we are turning onto a path with a dead end—resource allocation problems have a mathematical solution, especially when given the agents’ utility functions and a set of resources. This is a dead end because not much more can be said after solving such a contrived problem. Instead, Buchanan wants economists to focus on “a unique sort of relationship, that which involves the cooperative association of individuals, one with another, even when individual interests are different.”
The body of economic knowledge is an essential element in the structure of human civilization; it is the foundation upon which modern industrialism and all the moral, intellectual, technological, and therapeutical achievements of the last centuries have been built. It rests with men whether they will make the proper use of the rich treasure with which this knowledge provides them or whether they will leave it unused. But if they fail to take the best advantage of it and disregard its teachings and warnings, they will not annul economics; they will stamp out society and the human race.
So, Kelton is right, in a way, though it’s not just MMT that provides a “job guarantee” for Austrian economists. It’s all of the bad ideas from resource allocation problem solvers; from the professional class of “economists” who argue on behalf of the state and the special interest groups who seek to steer it in their favor; from the socialists, Marxists, Keynesians, monetarists, mercantilists, totalitarians, and warmongers. And it’s not really a job guarantee but a duty to expand economic understanding because it inoculates the public from embracing or tolerating the very ideas that threaten human flourishing and survival.
Praxeology, the science, is something that is the foundation of what makes human life worth living. Without the science of human action, everything else is for nought because there are no pointers on what to do, why to do it and when to do it. The Austrians seem to be on task but not the task the statists want economists to be on because Austrians are not just statist apologists.
Ludwig von Mises: "They are lackeys for special interest groups who want to steer government policy in a way that is advantageous for their clients."
Literally true. In fact, that's where our skills have the most market value.
That being said, a good economist can also provide a lot of wisdom and see through a lot of bullshit.
An insightful colleague in my field likes to ask people regarding their jobs, "Do you create surplus or just move it around?"
reply
Yep, you have it, there. The whole thing is that the mainstream economists seem to be lackeys for the special interest group called THE STATE!! They seem to only come up with solutions that have good effects only for their paymasters. I am sorry to say that this seems to be a case for a lot of academia in all areas and specialities.
reply
Yeah, I mean it's true for a lot of jobs in law, finance, accounting, etc, etc.
Even software engineering these days... if your job is just to design algorithms to draw peoples eyeballs, I'd say you're just moving surplus around, not creating it.
reply
It is always fun to move surpluses around, especially when you have very sticky fingers. They are sticking their beaks in up to the nostrils, methinks.
reply
I definitely want to push back on this idea. Resource allocation is a central part of economics and it only has mathematical solutions when you pretend to know things that are not only impossible to know, but also likely diverge from reality.
i.e. preferences are unknowable and don’t necessarily conform to the assumptions that make micro models solvable.
reply
I think pushing back on the idea of mathematical solutions was the whole theme of the article. It also pushes back on the idea that other theories of economics are valid because they miss the basics, as you pointed out, like preferences determining the distribution of goods and wealth. Time preference is another heavily ignored idea by a lot of mainstream economists.
reply
There's a bit of a throwing out the baby with the bathwater thing going on.
There is a lot of emphasis on solving the solvable mathematical models, which isn't particularly important. It's worth going over, because there are definitely things to be learned from those solutions. They have real implications.
Rather than stop there, though, is would be more valuable to then explore what happens when the assumptions that led to those solutions are relaxed. This is also done in PhD programs, but it's less emphasized.
reply
Perhaps a point of disagreement would be that the mathematical solutions have a lot to do with reality. I question that. Some of the models suggest homo economus will do things that nobody, in their wildest imaginations would think of doing. Even after examining the premises of the model to see where things went awry, it is hard to figure out the flaws. Even relaxing assumptions give erroneous predictions.
I just wonder, myself, how much back-testing these theorists are doing. Another point is, that they do not seem at all interested in anything that seems to be fairly accurate at predicting behaviors as well as back-testing as valid.
reply
The solutions are a useful starting point, though, or the can be. Many of the assumptions about preferences are reasonable-ish, so you can at least have a baseline solution. Then you can think about how changes to the initial assumptions might shift the solution.
reply
I just wonder where they are coming up with preferential assumptions, is it from interviews, questionnaires or from actual observations of real purchases? They would all be erroneous if they are used as assumptions because none of them show real preferences for the next choice, and that includes purchase observations due to diminishing returns factor changing preferences. So, wouldn’t the starting assumptions always be incorrect?